Broadcasting Programming And The Audience

скачати

Broadcasting, Programming, And The Audience Essay, Research Paper

Broadcasting, Programming, and The Audience

Steiner’s Model

Steiner’s model on programming preferences and broadcasting choices

tries to show how stations come to the conclusion of what programming to show.

This model goes on the assumption that broadcasters will go after the largest

audience possible.

Going on the information given about this hypothetical situation, we can

predict what each of the four stations in this market will show.

There are three distinct audience preferences. The first groups of 1200

viewers has a first programming preference of sitcoms and a second choice of

soaps. The second group numbers 900 viewers and would pick cops first and soaps

second. The third group, 500 viewers, likes soaps first and sitcoms and their

second choice.

This model says that the audience will watch their first choice first

and then the second choice, but only is their first choice is not available.

Let’s say that the Federal Communications Commission licenses station A

in their market. Looking at the viewer preferences, station A would start to

broadcast soaps. By show soaps, it would capture a market of 2600 viewers. All

viewers would watch because soaps is their first choice or it is their second

choice but their first is not available.

The FCC then offers a license to station B. After examining the audience

sizes, stations B also starts to show soaps. By programming to this audience, it

splits the soaps market with station A and both of them have 1300 viewers.

Station B does not pick another programming because no other choice can

offer more than 1300 viewers.

When the FCC offers a license to station C, things will definitely

change in this market. Station C sees the biggest audience available is the

sitcom market with 1200 viewers.

But when station C takes that 1200 viewers from the soap audience which

hold sitcoms as their first choice, station A and B will both drop to 700

viewers. They now have to make a decision. Both can find larger markets

elsewhere.

One station, and it does not matter which one, will switch to cop shows.

For this hypothetical, station B would choose cops for 900 viewers.

Station A, who still is showing soaps, now only has 500 viewers. It does

not like that, so it starts to show sitcoms. Audience 3, with 500 viewers, now

is watching sitcoms because there are no soaps out there. Station A and C are

both showing sitcoms and are splitting a viewer audience of 1700 for 850 each.

Now that the viewers are confused about what station is showing what,

the FCC offers a fourth license to station D. After examination, station D

decides to start broadcasting sitcoms in competition with stations A and C. All

three stations have an audience share of 566. That is more than the 500 soap

viewers or splitting the 900 cops viewers with station B.

Although Steiner’s model is not too far off what happens in today’s

television landscape, it does have a couple of drawbacks that keeps it from

being a true model.

Steiner does not take into consideration that some audiences are more

valuable to advertisers than others. Because advertisers want certain viewers,

stations might program to that audience to attract more advertising dollars.

Steiner also assumes that as stations go into competition with another

station, they will split the audience equally. That is not always the case.

Viewers will watch the station they believe has the better quality, even if

there are two or three stations showing the same thing.

This model does offer some insights on how stations and networks make

decisions. Just look at the TV Guide and see how many sitcoms there are on any

given night.

This also shows why some minority viewers never get programming directed

at them. The stations are going to the majority audiences which have larger

numbers. The minority viewer preferences, under these model, have to have

another station before they get to see their shows, in this situation.

First Copy Costs

First copy costs in the newspaper industry are the fixed costs of owning

a paper and printing the first one.

First copy costs include the money spend on items that are necessary for

the newspaper to be printed. These fixed costs do not vary as the number of

papers increases or decreases. Because they do not vary, they are very important

and must be covered by advertising and subscriptions.

These fixed costs include the physical plant, the presses, the pressmen,

reporters, photographers, other staff members and the delivery trucks.

The interesting things about fixed costs is that you have to have them.

You can not scrimp or just not buy them. To cut corners, a paper does not hire

reporters, but how does it cover the local news? Whether or not you print a

paper, you still must pay for that stuff.

To figure the first copy costs of a newspaper, the fixed costs and the

cost of the paper and ink of the first issue off the press are added together.

For instance, let’s say that the fixed costs of a newspaper is $1 million and

the first issue costs $1 to print. The first copy costs $1,000,001.

Looking at this, it sounds like newspapers would never make any money,

but we have not figured in variable costs. These include the paper, ink and

related costs of running the press. As the quantity of papers goes up, these

prices usually go down. As the quantity continues to go up, the average cost

comes down and each paper gets cheaper and cheaper.

First copy costs keep many papers from owning their own presses. Large

dailies must own their own presses in order to meet distribution deadlines and

ensure that their paper gets printed on time. Smaller papers can not afford that

first copy cost, so they have to contract with other to print their paper.

First copy costs are a determining factor in how a paper is operated.

Whether it owns it own presses or not, the size of its staff and how often it

prints is all tied into these first copy costs.

Economy of Scale with Cable TV

By the nature of the beast, cable operators normally get exclusive

franchises to supply a community with their cable service; so talking about

competition in the cable industry sounds like an oxymoron. But there are signs

that it might actually compete in a way.

Less than 50 cities in the United States are overbuilt, or have more

than one cable provider. Yet studies show that those overbuilt cities have lower

basic cable subscription rates, $14.31 compared to $17.31.

Can competition within the cable system be created?

Probably not. The barriers against entry for new cable operators in a

specific market are great.

To begin with, the new operator must get a franchise agreement with that

city. The incumbent franchise will not stand still for this. Those in the local

government also will fear that the incumbent franchise might change benefits or

disturb the local political situation.

Economics of Scale would suggest that the incumbent would have lower

average costs because they are already there and have a better distribution

system. The second franchise would have high entry costs because they have to

string their own cable and many times they have to bury the new cable. This

additional work means high construction costs and community aggravation as they

tear up roads and yards.

The incumbent can employ delay tactics to make it very hard to start up

new franchises. From political pressure to lawsuits to dropping price and

keeping their customers happy, delays will make the new guy on the block

discouraged and out.

Within the cable operator networks, like TCI or CableVision, networks

themselves own or have a financial interest in some of the channels they carry.

Time-Warner owns TBS, CNN and a host of other channels started by the Turner

Broadcast System.

Although this sounds like a serious violation of the anti-trust laws, no

contest has been put up against this practice. In fact, it has been shown that

multi-system operators and overbuilt cities’ operators are more likely to

provide channels owned by other networks.

Carrying their own channels allows networks to increase profits and

helps keep subscription rates down. And, as a practical matter, cable systems

need channels to put out there for people to watch. Owning or having financial

interest in channels ensures that they have programming to carry.

With all the things going against the competition of cable systems, the

market demand for cable is elastic. The Crandall study, sponsored by TCI, showed

that an elastic rate of 2.2 means that as subscription rates go up 1 percent,

2.2 percent of the subscribers will cancel their service.

As the market show elasticity, the reality is that is normally does not

work that way. To persuade subscribers to take their higher rates, cable

operators offer new channels along with the rate hike. The number of channels

has traditionally been a measure of quality and as “quality” goes up, so can the

rates.

Cable in the near future will see some competition from sectors outside

of the cable industry. The Telecommunication Act of 1996 will make it easier for

telephone and utility companies to go head to head with the cable operators.

This might change the competition landscape of cable TV.

Programming To the Minority Audiences

Because networks and broadcasters look to capture the largest audience

possible, many times the minority tastes are ignored. These minorities now have

more choices today than they did before as technology expands.

Steiner’s model described how broadcasters went after larger audiences

and skip over minority tastes. As technology advances and more stations are

introduced, Steiner’s model would suggest that those minority tastes were met.

In a situation where government regulates a small number of broadcast

stations, minority taste audiences have little recourse. The only option that

they have is to petition the government to force the stations to program to them.

Such was the case with religious groups. They got the Federal Communications

Commission to make stations allocate time for specific religions and their shows.

In a government sponsored market with a limited number of channels, some

programming for the minority tastes will appear. The government would sponsor a

channel that showed minority taste programming. On the down side here, the other

broadcasters will continue to ignore minority tastes because their needs are met

somewhere else. Broadcasters will continue to aim for the majority markets.

Today, with an unlimited number of channels available, minorities have

programming provided to them. Those with minority tastes can now start their own

channel to cater strictly to themselves. Whatever their tastes, they will have

it.

The benefit of unlimited channel supply is that the market audience

keeps getting more and more programming. Once someone see a type of programming

work and make money, they might go after the same market. Broadcasters who once

avoid that type of programming can now start another channel and tap into that

market without detracting from its majority audience programming.

As the technology improves and allows more and more minority groups to

get involved with broadcasting, we will start to see a sharp increase in

specialty channels; more than what we currently see.

Додати в блог або на сайт

Цей текст може містити помилки.

A Free essays | Essay
16.4кб. | download | скачати


Related works:
Broadcasting
Digital Broadcasting
Global Broadcasting Systems
Regulations On Radio Broadcasting
GOVERNMENT REGULATIONS ON RADIO BROADCASTING
Music Television Station Mtv And Public Broadcasting
The Audience Is Everything
A Hanging Audience
Audience In Frankenstein
© Усі права захищені
написати до нас